This Sunday Essay begins with skepticlawyer's On simplifying without simplification. This is an example of a brief written for a Scottish client on the causes and consequences of the global financial crisis. I found it interesting in a professional sense because of its topic and also because a fair bit of my work over the years has involved the preparation of just this type of briefing. As you would expect from SL, it's clearly written.
The brief includes this rather striking graph showing Australia's astonishingly good relative performance over the period. SL comments:
That said, Australian banks remained fairly conservative in their lending practices in the lead-up to the financial crisis, a practice allied with higher interest rates set by the Reserve Bank of Australia. This had the extraordinary consequence that Australia did not experience the GFC.
It is correct, I think, to say that the Australian financial system was arguably more conservative and indeed better regulated. It is also correct that the higher interest rates gave the Reserve Bank more room to move. It is not correct to say that Australia did not experience the GFC, nor is it correct that more conservative lending policies plus higher interest rates were the reason why Australia came through the GFC so well in relative terms. I say this not to carp at SL's analysis, but because of the tendency in analysis to attach too much weight to financial and regulatory issues in explaining Australia's better performance. These were necessary but not sufficient conditions.
Two important things happened in the year leading up to the GFC. First, Australia's balance of trade improved quite remarkably. Secondly, and somewhat perversely given the first, the value of the Australian dollar declined. In combination, the two provided something of a natural buffer to the GFC. They were a key part of the reason why I took a contrary position at the time on the likely implications for Australia of the GFC.
When the GFC hit, it affected Australia in two main ways.
Australian banks dependent on international markets for wholesale funds experienced just the same type of borrowing difficulties as banks elsewhere. This did flow on to lending. Australian borrowers faced credit constraints similar to those experienced elsewhere, if on a somewhat smaller scale. The psychological impacts were just as important.
I was in China in September 2008 when the GFC hit its most critical phase. From my hotel room in Shanghai I watched the crisis unfold.
Returning to Australia, I was quite astonished at the pessimism I found. The gloom was affecting everything. It really was.
One can argue about the scale and composition of the Australian Government response to the crisis. Was it too much? Was money wasted?
Regardless of these issues, the key point is that the quick response at multiple levels from bank guarantees to cash splashes directly targeted both the pervasive gloom and key economic variables. I remain of the view that these responses were a major achievement for the then Rudd Government and the institutions of Government including Treasury.
The capacity of the Government and the Reserve Bank to respond were greatly aided by the country's fiscal position. With no net Commonwealth Government debt and a good budget position, both the Government and the Reserve Bank had considerable freedom to move. There is a lot of debate in Australia at the present time centred on the failure of Governments, past and present, to take proper advantage of the benefits offered by the minerals' boom.
I agree, but in relative terms, we have done pretty well. We were able to stimulate the economy at a level comparable to countries elsewhere, but actually come out better off in relative terms in things such as budget deficit and Government debt than most countries. This brings in the last variable, China.
China kept growing during the crisis. Whereas much of the rest of the developed world struggled to stabilise, Australia experienced a minerals boom based on Chinese demand. You don't have to be very good to do well when things break your way!
Australia truly has been a lucky country. This brings me to my last point.
I don't think that Australia actually offers much in the way of lessons about how to handle things such as the GFC. There were things we did right, but we were also just lucky. If the value of our currency had not declined at just the right time, if China had stalled instead of growing, things would have been very different. In a perfect economic storm, we had perfect economic luck, allowing competent but not perfect economic management to play its part.
Now we appear to have overtaken Spain to become the twelfth largest economy in the world. Who would have believed it? Just remember, it's not us who did it.
7 comments:
A good post Jim.
I don't wish to do my usual 'hogging' on either blog but I'd be really interested in seeing the effects of a) the shift in employment from 'job for life' to casual and contract work (described euphemistically as a 'employment mobility') and flowing from that b) the relative unemployment experience of those large economies which suffered worse.
I guess a hobbyhorse but if you pursue national economic policies and business restructuring practices which result in a part of your workforce shipped overseas, then it becomes very difficult for the ultimate party - the individual borrower - to maintain the servicing of any loan. In this, Australia was again luckier than most - with the maintenance of relatively full employment via our 'boom' industry sectors.
kvd
Actually, kvd, I don't think any of us mind you hogging at either place. Hog away!
You raise an interesting issue. There is a balance question. My impression is that greater labour mobility does improve market responses. But when, and this is something I have written about, that mobility translates to greater insecurity, it affects all sorts of behavior patterns.
When it hollows out the economy, the economy as a whole is less able to respond to change.
'Job for life'? OMG, we're not living in a Stalinist system - even if our cretinous government wouldn't recognise flexibility if it bit them.
Anon you have to be either very young or quite disingenuous to fail to acknowledge the changing employment pattern in Australia over the last, say, 30 years. The term 'job for life' is a widely recognised one, but if you don't believe me Google Australia+'job for life' to see just how many papers, articles and even government publications exist which reference this as a shorthand for a movement away from single employer long term employment to casual, contract and/or industry mobility.
It is not part of some Stalinist plot. It is not a 'good thing' or a 'bad thing'; it is just something to be recognised so that any discussion can get on to more significant and/or interesting matters, instead of arguing of such basics.
kvd
OMG indeed, anon. I think that kvd made the point about analysis quite clearly. But really! Stalinist system? get real.
kvd: even if the search term you suggest were to yield evidence consistent with your assertion (which it doesn't), you in any case contradict yourself (your post, 28 Oct) by clearly distinguishing between "employment from job for life" and "casual and contract work" ... Oh dear! And 'Stalinist system'... well, perhaps a little bit of licence; but this doesn't go astray.
Hi anon. A question. What do you hope to achieve from this discussion?
Post a Comment